Wednesday, September 19, 2012

The Issue of Human Rights

The present constitution of Indonesia contains several chapters on human rights. Equal treatment before the law, non-discrimination among citizens, the right to have jobs and education, freedom of association and expression, and freedom of religion are all mentioned in the constitution. But in practice, some straying from these ideals have occurred. As many Asian countries, Indonesian takes the view that human rights should be interpreted locally and that the country should not follow the Western interpretation of it blindly (Budiardjo 1991). Promotion and protection of these rights must be conducted in a way that balances individual and collective rights, with individual rights being second to collective rights. 

However, the problem arises about the meaning of collective rights and who has the authority to determine whether a right is individual or collective. This has often generated disagreement between the community and the government. For example, when the government needs land for urban development, the bureaucracy always employs the principle of public interest to “force” the people out of their land or to determine the compensation price for land at low level, despite the fact that in many cases the land bought is then given to private companies to develop housing complexes or supermarkets. When conflicts arise between the government and the “forced” sellers of land, the court often sides with the government. 

In terms of labour relations, workers still have difficulties in protecting their interests. The state tends to over-protect industrialists so as to boost exports, leaving workers to protest for wage hikes and to demand their right to set up unions. 

Wages in Indonesia are considered one of the lowest in Asia (Werner International Management Consultant 1990). In 1992, the minimum wage set by the government for Jakarta was Rp 3000 (U$ 1.5) per day, while in other areas it was Rp 1,250 (U$0.50) per day. These wage levels are not sufficient to sustain the minimum human need. The situation gets worse when many industrialists fail to pay their labourers even the mininmum wage level. According to the Labour Minister, in Jakarta about 3 percent of industrialists do not pay the minimum level of wages (Tempo, 19 February 1994). The industrialists also tend to use child labour or refuse to give pregnancy leave for women workers (Tempo, 25 September 1993). 

To fight for their rights, workers have only one organization (SPSI, the All Indonesian Labour Federations) which is recognized by the government. Any effort to establish other labour organizations is quashed. This can be seen in the move made, for example, by Haji Princen to set up the Independent Labour Union Setiakawan (Tempo, 1991), and by Mochtar Pakpahan to establish the Indonesian Labour Welfare Union, both of which were blocked by the government. 

Worse still, there is a stipulation in law which says that workers who want to set up unions must obtain agreement from the management of industries or factories where they are working. In fact, not many owners allow their workers to set up labour organizations. In addition, strikes by workers and lay-offs by employers are prohibited (Budiman 1992). The Department of Labour is also actively involved in labour disputes, having the right to invite involvement by the military. In many cases, the military has taken over problems and handled the disputes in a way that has tended to protect the interest of the industrialists more than that of the workers. 

The prohibition of workers from setting up organizations has a historical basis. During the Old Order period (1950-65), labour organizations had been used by political parties, especially the Communist Party to mobilize workers against the government. Labour unrests were a major cause of political instability that inflicted great damage on the economy and contributed to the fall of the Old Order.

(Continued on title : "The President")

Tuesday, September 18, 2012

Political Parties

The New Order Government inherited the state’s traumatic experience with political parties and this has strongly affected its attitude towards such parties. In the 1950s, the government was under parliamentary system which suffered badly from political instability, which included regional rebellions. In that period of “Liberal Democracy” (1950-59), Indonesia had about fifty parties competing with one another on the basis of ethnicity and primordialism. No Cabinet lasted for more than six months because of the absence of a majority party. There was also suspicion in the regions that the centre had too much power in their hands, leaving only limited autonomy to the regions. Furthermore, the rapid development of the Communist Party caused anxiety among other parties and the majority of army leaders at the regional and local levels. These two factors, among others, were behind the regional rebellions during 1957-60 in West Sumatra and Sulawesi. 

When Soeharto took office in 1966, his attitude towards the role of political parties was a reflection of the earlier political trauma. The victory of Golkar (which is strongly supported by the military) in the 1971 elections (the first elections held in the New Order era) put the government in a good position to propose new political regulations. In 1973, the government reduced the number of political parties from ten to three through amalgamation. Some Islamic-based parties were grouped into the PPP while the nationalist, Christians and Catholics were grouped into the PDI. 

Soon, it became clear that forced regrouping like this would create serious internal conflicts among the parties. The traditional Muslim groups have always been in conflict with the modernist Muslims in the PPP, while the nationalists have always failed to come to agreement with the Christians and the Catholics in the PDI. Internal conflicts have also occurred in PPP and PDI party conferences, and this has usually invited the intervention of the government. The frequent conflicts have become a factor in the failure of the parties to consolidate or strengthen their organizations, while the government has steadily accumulated power through its party machinery, Golkar. 

Most parties have become very dependent on the government for several reasons. For example, financially, the parties would not be able to conduct party congresses or election campaigns without massive aid from the government. Thus, the government has easily dictated policies to the parties and exerted much influence on leadership selection within the parties. There is little chance for the parties to select their own leaders without the agreement of the government. 

The PPP and PDI have had difficult times in trying to raise funds from businessmen because their election prospects are uncertain. The public are unsure of the benefit they can obtain from their donations to the parties. Intellectuals also have the same question in mind when they are approached by the parties. Support for Golkar on the other hand is ample because it has the ability to provide facilities and protection to businessmen and even positions in the government for intellectuals who support it. 

As noted earlier, since 1987 there have been changes in the attitude of businessmen and intellectuals. Some of them have begun to support, and get involved in, the management of the PPP and the PDI with the aim of defeating Golkar in the cause of democracy. However, their numbers are still small and it is likely they will not grow significantly in size by the time of the next elections in 1997.

(Continued on title : "The Issue of Human Rights")

Monday, September 17, 2012

The Parliament


Today in Indonesia, political institutions are not free from government intervention. Although some changes have occurred over the last decade, politics and policy remain the monopoly of the highest levels of the civilian and military bureaucracies (Jackson 1980). The role of the legislative body (DPR or Dewan Perwakilan Rakyat) is limited although there is some improvement compared to the 1970s.

Since the 1971 elections, Golkar has held the majority of seats in the DPR, leaving the PPP (Partai Persatuan Pembangunan or United Development Party) and the PDI (Partai Demokrasi Indonesia or Indonesian Democratic Party) as minority parties. Political domination by Golkar is strengthened by the presence of Members of Parliament (MPs) who have been appointed by the government: they are from functional or professional groups, with military officers accounting for about one-third of the total number of MPs (about 400 MPs).

Furthermore, since 1971, the electoral system has been marked by a multi-member constituency or proportional system in combination with a list system. Enforcement of this system has caused the alienation of MPs from their constituencies. Under this system, MP candidacies are determined by the Council of Party Leaders (DPP) of each political party. As such, some MPs may merely have access to or connections with the DPP and may not be familiar with their constituencies. Many MPs have no knowledge about their constituencies since they live in Jakarta or originally came from some regions but represent other regions. A candidate from West Java, for example, may represent East Java although he has never lived in East Java at all.

As a result, not many MPs actually possess the requisites to become representatives of the public. To remain in office they merely need support from the party councils and not from the constituencies. Thus, their position in the DPR is not dependent on public support but on support from the party councils. On the basis of this fact, they tend to support party policies rather than the aspirations of the public. The dominant position of party councils is strengthened by the fact that the councils have the power to recall MPs from their positions in the DPR if they violate party discipline or if the councils receive a warning from the government.

The mechanism and procedures in the DPR also place limitations on MPs in proposing new laws. A proposal needs the agreement of two factions before it can be an agenda item for discussion. In fact, it is difficult for minority parties such as the PPP and the PDI to get the agreement of other parties, especially from Golkar as the majority party. This arrangement reduces the possibility of opposition in the DPR.

As noted earlier, there have been changes in the attitudes of MPs over the last decade. They have been more vocal in criticizing the government. The Bapindo (Bank Pembangunan Indonesia, or Indonesia Development Bank) financial scandal, for example, was discussed in 1994 as a result of investigations by an MP from Golkar. But such MPs are few in number and come mainly from either the military faction or from Golkar. The majority of the MPs still prefer to keep silent to avoid being recalled by their party councils. In addition, for many younger MPs, especially from Golkar, their seats in Parliament guarantee them a good life for at least five years. In research on the performance of MPs was the need to have job (Santoso 1993). Thus, it is easily understood why in many parliamentary debates MPs prefer to keep silent.

(Continued on title : "Political Parties")

Sunday, September 16, 2012

Press Freedom


As stated above, the mass media in Indonesia have been allowed more freedom but some limitations remain. The government, for example, has the authority to ban any mass media if its news or analysis has, according to the government, undermined the credibility of the government or threaten the stability and security of the country. Since 1970, some media have been closed down; the last occurred in magazines (Tempo and Editor) and one tabloid (Detik). Such power is reinforced by the fact that the Indonesian presses have to seek permission from the government for any publication. Additionally, the government has to approve the composition of the editorial board before letters of permission are issued.

The government’s closure of the three publications mentioned above met with protests from students. Yet, the protests lasted only a week and people quickly forgot about the issue. The editors of the publications were left with the view that they had to exercise self-censorship. Such self-censorship is also occasioned by a stipulation in the press laws that “the national press has [both] the freedom as well as responsibility”. The final say on press freedom and its responsibility lies, of course, with the government.

Another factor behind the ban of the three publications was an intra-elite conflict involving three parties: the Muslims, the Nationalist, and the Catholics. The three publications were closed down after they continually wrote about Indonesia’s acquisition of warships from Germany which, according to them was too expensive. The three publications also reported that the key figure behind the acquisition was Minister for Research and Technology, B.J. Habibie, a minister who is strongly affiliated to the Muslim group through position as Chairman of ICMI (Ikatan Cendekiawan Muslim Indonesia or Association of Muslim Intellectuals).

Reports on the warships were considered conspiratorial, aimed at undermining the reputation and political influence of Habibie as well as the Muslim groups by the mass media sponsored by the nationalist. Although the chief editors of Tempo (Gunawan Muhammad and Fikri Jufri) were not connected to the nationalist groups, they were categorized (by their opponents) as nominal Muslims. Some members of the editorial board of the magazine, however, were considered nationalists and they were believed to have written the articles about Habibie. The Chief Editor of Detik tabloid was also considered by his opponents as a nationalist. Criticisms of Habibie were also made by the mass media owned by Christian, and specifically Catholic groups.

Prior to the closing down of these publications, President Soeharto on his visit to Lampung (in south Sumatra) had explained that all accusations made by the media about Habibie were wrong because the decision to buy the warships was made b him and that Habibie did not know about it. The President claimed that he had given Habibie instructions to contact the German Government for the purchase of the ships. The President had heard about the possibility of buying the ships from a leading businessman close to him. In the speech in Lampung, the President indirectly asked the authorities to enforce sanctions on the media which were engaging in insinuations and spreading false information. The case of Tempo shows that the government still has much power over the press.

(Continued on title : "The Parliament")

Saturday, September 15, 2012

Gudeg



Gudeg (gudheg Java language) is the typical food of Yogyakarta and Central Java which is made from young jackfruit cooked with coconut milk. It took me hours to make this dish. Brown is usually generated by teak leaves are cooked simultaneously. Gudeg eaten with rice and served with thick coconut milk (areh), chicken, eggs, tofu and sambal goreng krecek.

There are different variants of gudeg, among others:

Dry Gudeg, which is served warm with areh thick, much thicker than coconut milk in cooking field.
Wet Gudeg, which is served with warm dilute areh.
Gudeg Solo, namely that arehnya warm white.

Friday, September 14, 2012

Sate Padang



Sate Padang is the name for the three types of variants in the sate of West Sumatra, the Sate Padang, Padang Panjang and Sate Sate Pariaman.

Sate Padang wearing materials beef, tongue, or jerohan (heart, intestine, and tetelan) with a thick peanut sauce seasoning (like porridge) plus a lot of chili so spicy taste.

Sate Padang Panjang satay sauce is distinguished by its yellow color whereas Pariaman satay sauce is red. Sense of both types of satay is also different. While sate Padang has a different flavor combination of both types of variants skewers on top.

The process of making

Fresh meat included big role in drums filled with water and soft boiled twice in order to use a different drum and water. Meat sliced ​​and covered with herbs and spices. While cooking water is used as a broth, ingredients to make satay sauce. Then the broth was mixed with 19 kinds of spices which have been smoothed (onion, garlic, turmeric, ginger, and lemongrass) was mixed with different kinds of chili. The whole spices and then put together and cooked for 15 minutes.

Sate itself is only burned when ordered, using charcoal from coconut shell.

Thursday, September 13, 2012

Tongkonan Toraja



Tongkonan is a traditional house of Toraja people. The roof is curved like a boat, consisting of bamboo structure (currently part tongkonan using zinc roof). At the front there is a row of water buffalo horn. The interior of the room used as a bed and kitchen. Tongkonan used also as a place tostore the bodies. Tongkonan derived from the word tongkon (meaning sit together). Tongkonandivided based on the level or role in society (social Stara Society Toraja). In front there tongkonanrice granary, the so-called 'grass'. Granary poles are made from palm tree trunks (Bangah) is currently partly already casted. At the front of the barn there are a variety of carvings, including a picture of chicken and sun, a symbol to resolve the matter.

Especially in Sillanan-Pemanukan (Tallu Lembangna) known by the term Ma'duangtondok tongkonanthere is Tongkonan Karua (eight home tongkonan) and Tongkonan A'pa '(four home tongkonan),which plays a role in the community.

Tongkonan karua consists of :
1. Tongkonan Pangrapa '(Kabarasan)
2. Tongkonan Sangtanete Jioan
3. Tongkonan Nosu (To intoi masakka'na)
4. Tongkonan Sissarean
5. Tongkonan ToPanglawa field
6. Tongkonan Tomanta'da
7. Tongkonan To'lo'le Jaoan
8. Tongkonan ToBarana '

Tongkonan A'pa 'consists of :
1. Tongkonan Peanna Guess'
2. Tongkonan To'induk
3. Tongkonan Karorrong
4. Tongkonan Tondok Bangla '(Pemanukan)

Many traditional houses in Sillanan tongkonan reputedly said, but according to the local community, that is said tongkonan only 12 as noted above. Another traditional house called banuapa'rapuan. Was said in Sillanan tongkonan is custom house where derivatives play a role in the localindigenous community. Descendants of tongkonan describe the social strata of society in Sillanan.Example Tongkonan Pangrapa '(Kabarasan) / holders of government power. If there are people whodied and deducted two buffaloes, one head of buffalo brought to Tongkonan Pangrapa 'to be dividedderivatives.

In community social Stara Sillanan on for over 3 levels, namely :
1. Ma'dika (blue blood / descendant of nobility);
2. To macaques (free man / free);
3. Kaunan (slaves), slaves still be subdivided into 3 levels.

Tongkonan, derived from the word 'tongkon' which means 'to sit together'. Tongkonan always be facing towards the north, which is considered as a source of life. Based on archaeological research, the Toraja came from Yunan, Tongkin Bay, China. Immigrants from China are then berakulturasi with the indigenous population of South Sulawesi.

Tongkonan the form of a wooden house on stilts, where water pools under the house is usually used as a byre. Tongkonan boat-shaped roof, which symbolizes the origin of the Toraja in Sulawesi who arrived by boat from China. At the front of the house, beneath the towering roof, mounted buffalo horns. The number of buffalo horn symbolizes the number of funerals that have been done by the family owners of tongkonan. On the left side of the house (facing west) is installed in the jaw who had slaughtered the buffalo, while on the right side (facing east) mounted jaw pig.In front there tongkonan rice granary, the so-called 'grass'. Granary poles are made from palm tree trunks ('Bangah') are slippery, so the mice can not go up into the barn. At the front of the barn there are a variety of carvings, including a picture of chicken and sun, a symbol to resolve the matter.In understanding the Toraja, tongkonan regarded as the 'mother', while the grass is as 'father'.Tongkonan function for residential, social activities, ceremonies, and fostering kinship. The inside of the house is divided into three parts, namely the northern, central, and south. The room in the northern part is called 'tangalok', serves as a living room, where children sleep, is also the place put offerings. The room section tengahdisebut 'Sali', serves as a dining room, family gatherings, where lay the dead, also the kitchen. The south room is called 'Sumbung', is a room for the head of the family. The room to the south is also considered a source of disease.The bodies of the dead not be buried immediately, but stored in tongkonan. Before the funeral, the bodies are deemed as 'the sick'.In order not to foul, the corpse was embalmed with formalin kind of traditional herb, which is made of betel leaf and banana juice. If the funeral will be conducted, first corpse stored in barns for 3 days.Toraja traditional coffin called 'erong', shaped for the female pig and buffalo for men. For the nobility, made erong shaped custom homes.

Wednesday, September 12, 2012

Sasak House


Sasak tribes is a native and ethnic majority in Lombok, NTB. As indigenous peoples, tribes have Sasak culture system as recorded in the book of essays Nagara Kartha Gama master Nala from Majapahit. In the book, the Sasak tribe called "Sak-Sak Lomboq Adhi Mirah." If the currently authored the book Sasak tribe has a culture of sustainable systems, the ability to still exist until now, this is one proof that the tribe is able to protect and preserve traditional .

One form of proof of Sasak culture is a form of building custom homes. House is not just a place to multifunction occupancy, but also have aesthetic and philosophical messages of its inhabitants, both the architecture and layout space. Sasak traditional houses on the roof shaped like a mountain, dive to the bottom with a range of about 1.5 to 2 meters above the ground. Roof and bubungannya (BUNGUS) made of beams, walls of woven bamboo, only has one small and no windows. Columns (kernel) is divided into Inan bale (holding area) which includes bale out (sleeping) and bale palace be a place to store wealth, the mother gave birth to space once before the buried corpse burried space. Dalem bale space equipped divan, kitchen, and sempare (a place to store food and other household appliances) are made from bamboo size 2 x 2 meters square or rectangular can. Furthermore there is sesangkok (living room) and the entrance to the pan. Between the bale and bale out the door and stairs palace there (three places) and the form of a mixture of ground floor with buffalo dung or horse, rubber and straw ash. Terraces, terraces (steps), used as a bridge between rural and bale bale palace.

Another thing that quite interesting to note from home Sasak traditional development patterns. In building the house, the Sasak adapt to the needs of family or group will not. That is, development is not just to mememenuhi family needs but also the needs of the group. Because the concept is, the housing complex Sasak culture appears regularly as harmonious life reflects the local population. Lombok traditional house form developed during the reign of the Karang Asem (17th century), in which the architecture of Bali Lombok married to architecture. In addition to shelter, the house also has an aesthetic, philosophical, and simple life of the residents in the past that rely on natural resources as a daily maintenance cost, as well as the development of the house. The floor of the house is a mixture of clay, rubber tree and darkvictory Banten (local term), plus the existing coke batteries in the rocks, ashes of burnt straw, then oiled with buffalo dung or horse at the top floor. Material to the floor of the house serves as gluten, also use to avoid the floor is not moist. Flooring materials to be used, by the people at Dusun Sade, considering buffalo dung or cow can not bersenyawa with clay which is the type of soil in the orchard.

Sasak traditional home construction was presumably associated with the Islamic perspective. Of stairs last three is the symbol of the human life cycle: birth, grow, and die. Also as batih family (father, mother, and children), or four-poster berugak symbol of Islam: Holy Quran, Hadith, Ijma, Qiyas). Junior and senior children in the age determined the location of his house. Parents' home at the highest level, followed by the eldest and youngest daughter was in the rock bottom. This is a teaching of moral values ​​that the sister in the attitude and acts should be the role models sister. The house facing east on the old symbolic meaning that it first receive / enjoy the warm morning sun rather than the young physically stronger. It also could mean, so leave the house to work and earn a living, people wish they had pleased God through the prayers of them, and it was noted that the door of his house facing east or opposite to the direction of the sun (west / test). Guests even have to stoop when entering a relatively short doors. Perhaps the bow position was indirectly hinted an existing ethics or honor to the host from the guest.

Then the barn, but to teach its citizens to live prudently and not extravagant for logistics stocks stored therein, can only be taken at certain times, such as once a month. Logistic materials (rice and palawija) shall not be dikuras out, but disisakan for urgent need, such as failing to anticipate harvest due to weather and crop damaging animals attack or material to provide syukuran if there is a family member died.

Berugak that is in front of the house, as well as a tribute to the things which the Lord, also serves as a living, receiving guests, also a control tool for the local people. For example, if you arrive at nine in the morning still sitting in berugak and do not leave home to work in the fields, farms, and farms, perhaps he is ill.

Since the process of planning a house built, the role of women or wife come first. For example, the distance usuk bamboo roof frame as wide as the head of the wife, the high storage kitchen tool (sempare) must be accomplished wife's arm, but the width of the body-sized door wife. To develop and rehabilitate the house done in mutual assistance in spite of food, the following building materials, provided by the host.

In the Sasak people, home is in the dimension of the sacred (holy) and the profane world) simultaneously. This means that traditional Sasak house as well as a shelter and gather the family members is also a place sacred rituals fulfilled as a manifestation of confidence in God, ancestral spirits (papuk blocks) bale (house spirits). Changes in the knowledge society, the increasing number of residents and changes in many other external factors (such as safety factors, geographical, and topographical) causes changes in the functional and physical form of the custom house. Nevertheless, the concept of development, such as architecture, layout, and retains the characteristic pattern is based on traditional philosophical values ​​which are transmitted from generation to generation.

Time and Location Selection
To get started building the house, find the appropriate time, be guided on the board warige who came from Adam and Tajul Tapel almanac Muluq. Not everyone has the ability to determine a good day, usually people who want to build a house to ask the customary leaders. Sasak people of Lombok believe that a good time to start building the house is in the third and twelfth month of the Sasak removal, which is the month Rabiul Awal and Muharram in the Islamic calendar. There is also and determines based on the names of people who will build the house. While most avoided months (abstinence) to build the house was in the month of Muharram and Ramadlan. In the second of this month, according to the faith community, houses built tend to invite disaster, such as disease, fire, confidential Rizqi, and so on.

Besides the question of a good time to start development, the Sasak are also selective in determining the location of the home stand. They believe that the incorrect location may result in less favorable to dedicate it. For example, they will not be developed on the former fireplace tumah, former landfills, the former pit, and the position of the road or rails GUBUG skewers. In addition, the Sasak people will not build a house opposite to the direction and size different from the first house there. According to them, violates the concept of an act against the taboo (maliq-lenget).

While the material needed to build the house, among others: the wooden brackets, bamboo, woven from bamboo for the walls, straw and coarse grass used for roofing, kotaran buffalo or horses as a mixture of materials to stiffen the floor, rubber tree and darkvictory Banten , ashes of straw, used as a mixture to stiffen the floor.

Tuesday, September 11, 2012

Rumah Betang


Rumah Betang is the typical traditional house found in various parts of Kalimantan, especially in upstream areas which usually becomes the center of the Dayak tribe settlements, where the river is the main transport pathway for the Dayak to perform a variety of mobility of everyday life like going to work to the fields where Dayak tribe fields are usually far from residential areas, or perform trade activities (the ancient Dayak tribes usually trade using the barter system with the mutual exchange of fields, orchards and livestock).

Special Interest forms and large houses will vary in different places. There are houses that reach lengths of Special Interest 150 meters wide and up to 30 meters. Special Interest Generally houses built in the form of a stage with a height of three to five feet off the ground. Special Interest tall building, I expect to avoid flooding during the rainy season that threatened areas upriver in Borneo. Some residential units can have more than one Special Interest houses hanging fruit the size of the household members of the residential community. Each household (family) occupies the chamber (room) that the barriers of a large house the Special Interest, in addition to the general Dayak tribes also have single houses built temporarily to perform agricultural activities, it is because awaydistances between fields with the settlement.

More than a building for residential Dayak tribe, Special Interest actual house is the heart of the social structure of the life of the Dayak people. Special Interest culture is a reflection of the togetherness in the daily life of the Dayak people. Special Interest in the house is every individual's life in households and communities are systematically arranged by mutual agreement set forth in the customary law. Common security, both from criminal interference or sharing food, the joys and sorrows as well as mobilization of manpower to work the fields. The main value that stands out in his home life is the value of togetherness Special Interest (communalism) among the citizens who inhabit it, regardless of the differences they have. From here we learn that the Dayak tribe is a tribe that respects difference. Appreciate the differences in ethnic Dayak tribe, religion or social background.




Monday, September 10, 2012

Honai House


Papua is home Honai typical inhabited by the Dani. Honai houses made of wood with a conical roof made of straw or reeds. Honai has a small door and no windows. Actually, the structure was built Honai narrow or small, windowless intended to withstand the cold mountains of Papua.

Honai consists of two floors of the first floor as a bed and a second floor for a place to relax, eat, and do crafts. Due to built 2 floor, Honai has approximately 2.5 meters high. In the middle of the house prepared a place for a bonfire to warm themselves. Honai house is divided into three types, namely for men (called Honai), women (called Ebei), and pigsty (called Wamai)

Honai ordinary house inhabited by 5 to 10 people. Honai house in one building used for a place to rest (sleep), other buildings for dining together, and the third building to the cattle pens. Houses Honai generally divided into two levels. Ground floor and first floor are connected by stairs from bamboo. The men slept on the ground floor in a circle, while the women slept on the floor

Inside the house Honai or Ebei, look no single household. Honai indeed be a home for people in the township Wamena. But for the beds, they only use dry grass as the base. Alas it will be replaced with new grass taken from the field or garden, if you've seen dirty. Inside Honai also no chairs or tables, they make the floor of the house made of soil as a cushion.

Inside the house Honai also no electric lights. For lighting, they make fire by digging the soil in the bottom floor of the house to be a furnace. Because Honai has no windows and illumination only from the fire, the atmosphere in the house will feel more and more dark when night falls.

In a housing complex occupied by one family and there are several Honai. The number indicates the number of wives Honai there, here found many men of more than one wife in particular tribal chiefs or Ondoafi.

Sunday, September 9, 2012

Coto Makassar


Coto Makassar or Coto Mangkasara is a traditional food of Makassar, South Sulawesi. These foodsmade ​​from offal (entrails) beef simmered in a long time. Mixed offal stew beef is then sliced ​​andseasoned with specially blended spices. Coto served in a bowl and eaten with rice cake and "burasa".Currently Coto Mangkasara already spread to various regions in Indonesia, starting at street stalls torestaurants. And planned to begin in November 2008 Coto Makassar will be one of the menu onGaruda Indonesia domestic flights to and from Makassar.

Rawon



Rawon is a traditional culinary heritage of East Java. Rawon a meat soup with a distinctive flavor, made with kluwek (Achariaceae). Rawon is a traditional food which is common in all regions of East Java and Central Java community east (Surakarta).

Rawon usually served with beef in a typical plate of white rice and warm. Moreover, ordinary people eat bean sprouts rawon with short spiked sauce, and salted eggs.

To make the traditional dishes that had national, spice consisting of onion, garlic, coriander, turmeric, chilli, kluwek, salt, and refined vegetable oils especially dahullu. Meanwhile, cut meat into small pieces. Blends that have been mashed, then sauteed until fragrant, with added lemon grass and galangal. After the distinctive fragrant scent of spices stir, drain stir the seasoning.

Kuah rawon obtained from boiled water Dading obtained before the meat is cut into pieces. The broth is then cooked again with seasonings and add the chops stir. When this process, the typical dark color comes from kluwek rawon beginning to show.

Feature

Rawon flavor is very distinctive flavors representing the country that are rich in spices and fragrant aroma. A plate rawon usually eaten during the day or night, and usually served separately with warm rice.

A distinctive feature is its presentation of Rawon with sauce of chili and onions, as well as short sprouts. Without short bean sprouts, rawon will tersa tasteless, because bean sprouts are what caused the short and sweet crunchy flavor in every bite rawon.

Another peculiarity is owned rawon because this dish can be one symbol of Javanese culture. Rawon often dubbed as a soup of black (black soup) from Java. When most of the soup is served in clear soup or watery, serving soup in a soup rawon jet black.

In addition to the privilege of flavor, rawon making process also requires high precision in order to balance the spices, such as kluwek, hazelnut, lime leaves, bay leaves, lemongrass, and shallots. Errors in the blended herbs and spices madankan all of which have a distinctive aroma and flavor, the problem is not easy. Therefore, although the ingredients together, not necessarily rawon produced has the same flavor.

Rawon is the nation's culinary heritage that should be preserved. Today the emerging creativity of the development of various taste rawon. Rawon now no longer appear conventional. Now, there rawon beef ribs, oxtail rawon, rawon lung, tongue rawon, rawon spleen, and so on. Everything is mixed in the glow of a black sauce with savory truly unforgettable.

Location

Rawon now you can enjoy in various regions in Java, especially East Java Province. Almost all the districts in East Java has a shop or restaurant rawon his trademark. Hence the popularity of that, rawon also be enjoyed in other cities outside the province of East Java, including Jakarta, Bandung and Surakarta.

Saturday, September 8, 2012

Sate (Satay)


Sate or satay or sometimes written satai is food made ​​from pieces of meat (chicken, goats, sheep,cows, pigs, fish, etc.) are cut into small pieces, and pinned with satay puncture is usually made ​​ofbamboo, then burnt using charcoal embers. Sate is then presented with a variety of seasonings(depends on satay recipe variations). 

Sate known from Java, Indonesia, but the sate is also popular in Southeast Asian countries such asMalaysia, Singapore, Philippines and Thailand. Satay is also popular in the Dutch-influenced cuisine of Indonesia which was once a colony. Japanese version is called yakitori. 

Satay recipes and how to manufacture a wide range of dependent variations and recipes of eachregion. Almost all types of meat can be made sate. As the country origin of satay, Indonesia has arich satay recipe variations, see the list of satay.

Usually the satay sauce. This sauce can be soy sauce, peanut sauce, or the other. To sate the duckpond full menu is satay, peanut sauce or sweet spices spicy seasoning (according to taste) and slices of tomato and cucumber. Then sate eaten with warm rice or, if in some areas served with rice cake.Sate sometimes eaten with rice cake.

Origin
Sate allegedly created by the street food trade in Java around the beginning of the 19th century,based on the fact that satay was popularized in the early 19th century, along with the increasing number of immigrants from Arabia to Indonesia. It is also the reason for the popularity of the use ofgoat and sheep meat as an ingredient sate favored by people of Arab descent.

Type
According to the material type of meat skewers
satay chicken, satay pufferfish, satay lamb, scallop satay, satay bat (made ​​of buffalo meat), kebabsflies (made ​​from mutton or chicken), sate lembat, pins satay, beef satay, shrimp satay, pork satay,satay rabbit, young egg satay, sate torpedo, pork satay, sate jamu, turtle satay, satay snail, snake satay.

By region 
Banjar satay, satay Betawi, Blora satay, sate Madura, Maranggi satay, satay Matang, Padang satay,satay Ponorogo, Tegal satay.

Friday, September 7, 2012

Rumah Gadang (Gadang House)



Houses gadang a Minangkabau traditional house. Gadang house has features that are very typical.The form is essentially a rectangular beam that expands upward. Melintangnya sharp curved linesand ramps in the middle of the lower. Curved roof of his house is very sharp like buffalo horns, while the curved body and home ramps like the hull. Roof made ​​of palm fiber. Form a curved roof andpointed upward is called gonjong. Because of its roof form gonjong, then the house is also homegadang bagonjong.

Gadang which form the roof like a buffalo horn is often associated with stories Tambo MinangkabauAlam. The story of victory in the event of Minang people fighting against the Javanese buffalo.

The forms resemble buffalo horns are very commonly used in the Minangkabau, either as symbol orthe jewelry. One of them in traditional clothes, namely tingkuluak tanduak (tengkuluk horn) toBundo Kanduang.

The origins of house gadang also often associated with travel stories Minangkabau ancestors. The legend says gadang Minangkabau house body shape that resembles a ship's body is to imitate theform of boat Minangkabau ancestors during the first. Boat ancestor is known as presumptuous.

According to the story, this sassy ancestors originally sailed into the upper Batang Kampar. After arriving in an area, the passengers and crew climbed ashore. This sassy also drawn to the land so as not decomposed by the water stream.

Presumptuous then supported by the timber to stand strong. Then, it was presumptuous to hang the screen on the roof with a rope attached to the pole presumptuous. Furthermore, because the screen is hanging very heavy, rope-rope to form arches that resemble gonjong. This presumptuous to make a temporary shelter. Furthermore, the passenger boat makes a dwelling house that resembles thosepresumptuous. Once the ancestors of the Minangkabau of this spread, the form continues to bepresumptuous that bergonjong as the characteristic shape of their home. Given thesecharacteristics, among them even his descendants become easier to recognize each other. They willeasily find out that the house had belonged to their relatives gonjong originating from the samesassy landed on the edge of Batang Kampar.

The sections in the House Gadang Minangkabau

Minangkabau traditional house is called house gadang is because the size of this house is big. Great in the Minangkabau language is gadarig. So, home gadang means big house. The inside of the house is aroom off the large sieve, except the bedroom. The room is off the main room consisting of taperingand space that is marked by poles. Pole house gadang berbanjar from the face to the back or from leftto right. Berbanjar mast from front to back mbnandai tapering, while the pole of right now to mark the space. So-called tapering is the room from front to back. The rooms are lined up from left to rightis called space.

Number of tapering depends on the big house. Usually the amount of tapering is two, three, fourclans. Number of rooms usually consist of an odd number between three and eleven. Gadang housesize depending onamount lanjarnya.

As a big house, then in the house there was gadang parts that have special functions. Another part of the house is the large sieve under the floor. This section is called the pit of a house gadang. Gadangunder the house is quite high and wide. These pools are usually used as a storehouse of agriculturalequipment or used as a women's weaving. All parts of this pit covered with a latticed ruyung rare.

Gadang house wall made ​​of wood, except the back of the bamboo. The wall board is installedvertically. At each connection board framed. All boards are filled with carvings. Sometimes the poleis in the well carved. Thus, ukirang is the dominant decoration in the home building gadangMinangkabau. Carvings here are not associated with beliefs that are sacred, but only as valuableworks of art decoration.

Thursday, September 6, 2012

Joglo


Joglo is a traditional house of Javanese society. Consisting of 2 main sections namely Pendapa anddeep. Pendapa this part is the front that have a large room Joglo without barriers, typically used toreceive guests or a playroom where children and family leisure. The inside is part of a room in thehouse bedroom, living room and other spaces that are more privacy. The characteristics of the building is on the roof pendapanya towering like a mountain.

Type of Building Joglo Variations
  1. Joglo limasan lawakan atau “joglo lawakan”.
  2. Joglo Sinom
  3. Joglo Jompongan
  4. Joglo Pangrawit
  5. Joglo Mangkurat
  6. Joglo Hageng
  7. Joglo Semar Tinandhu
  8. Joglo Lambang Sari


Pecel


Pecel is food Culinary Cultural heritage of Indonesia. This culinary already existed since the Dutch colonial period. The proof, in Suriname, the former Dutch colony, there is food there, although there are differences in flavor and taste its contents, because the taste and the situation there (Suriname).Pecel usually made from vegetable stew of spinach, bean sprouts, long beans, basil, daun turi, Krai (a type of cucumber) or other vegetables are served with sauce poured pecel. The concept is similar to pecel dish salad dishes from Europe. Both use the same fresh vegetables as a main ingredient and use toppings. The difference is, if the salad using mayonnaise as a topping, then use the sauce pecel pecel. 

While Pecel version of Lombok is a food typical of Lombok dibut of kale and sprouts and fresh tomato sauce and chili paste. This food is very well known in the community. The main ingredients of the sauce pecel is peanuts and chilies are mixed with other ingredients such as kaffir lime leaves, garlic, tamarind, brown sugar and salt. Pecel often served with fried tempeh, peanut peanut brittle, peanut brittle dried shrimp, peanut brittle soy, or rice plates. In addition pecel also usually served with warm white rice plus chicken or jerohan. Way of presenting can be in a plate or in a folded banana leaves, called pincuk. This dish is similar to the gado-gado, although there are differences in the materials used. Pecel spicy flavor that is characteristic of the sting of this cuisine.

Wednesday, September 5, 2012

The Politics of Openness


Since the mid-1980s, political participation has been allowed to increase through the process of so-called politik keterbukaan (political openness). The growth of the economy and improvement in the level of education of the people have impacted on the government’s political attitude. One of the results of economic and educational development has been the increase in public political awareness over the last twenty years. Demands for more participation have also been strengthened by international pressure, related to foreign aid when donor countries look closely at a recipient country’s record of democratization, human rights and environmental protection.

Meanwhile, the academic community has been given more freedom to criticize the government. Academics are allowed to voice their opinions and criticism on government policies in the mass media, a freedom they did not enjoy in the previous decade. Intellectuals and students have formed themselves into various discussion groups and regularly give feedback to the government and the bureaucracy. The press also enjoys more freedom as can be seen in their relatively liberal selection, analysis, and presentation of articles.

The government’s attitude towards opposition groups has also changed significantly. An opposition group known as Petisi 50 which for more than a decade was barred from holding meetings, visiting foreign countries and even engaging in business activities, was given a chance to reconcile itself with the government. Minister of Research and Technology B.J. Habibie took the initiative in arranging a meeting between President Soeharto and the top leader of Petisi 50, Retired General A.H. Nasution in the presidential palace. Habibie also invited another leader of Petisi, Ali Sadikin (former Governor of Jakarta) together with other leading figures of the group to visit PT. PAL (a dockyard company, which is part of the “eight strategic industries” advocated and nurtured by Habibie) in Surabaya. This was the first invitation given to Petisi members by a high official, and though remaining critical of the government, their criticisms have not been as sharp as was previously the case.

However, some people still doubt the intention of the government to democratize because, according to them, the government is not nurturing the tree of democracy. Some even suspect that the government has adopted a double standard. They argue that, on the one hand, the government allows the public to criticize the government but, on the other, it still maintains many restrictions. It is widely believed that whenever the government feels that critics have gone too far it will use force to limit freedom. The term “rubber-band” policy (Jakarta Post, 2 June 1994; Alfian 1991) clearly describes this approach.

It should be remembered that some opposition leaders remain prohibited from organizing or taking part in seminars or meeting unless they secure permission from the police. Thus far, the opposition has not challenged this illiberal measure in court. Summoning government officials to court is considered useless because in most cases the government wins.

(Continued on title : "Press Freedom")

The Growth of the Economy

It is difficult to deny that under the New Order significant economic progress has been made. A stated above, the New Order inherited from Soekarno an economic system characterized by spiralling inflation of up to 600 per cent in 1965 and a scarcity of goods and services. In the 1990s, however, Indonesia has experienced consistently high or at least moderate economic growth. Even in 1982, when Indonesia was hit by the step decline in international oil prices, its annual rate of economic growth was still above 2 per cent.

The New Order has also successfully reduced the incidence of poverty. In 1976, the proportion of poor throughout. Indonesia was 40.36 per cent of the total population, while in 1987 it was 17.44 per cent. According to the Central Bureau of Statistics, in 1990 it was further reduced to 14.33 per cent (Syahrir 1992, p. 26).

The increase of educational facilities and the growth in the number of students especially at the elementary school level has also been phenomenal. Facilities in public health have also improved. in every sub-district (kecamatan), the government has established a Community Health Centre (Puskesmas) led by a medical doctor under a programme called Inpres Doctor (under which a medical doctor must serve in sub-districts as compulsory public service for three years after graduation). In each village there is one Posyandu (Community Service Centre) which provides services, especially medical services, for villagers. The centre is led by village officials who, among other things, have the task of calling for a medical doctor from the sub-district.

The flow of information has also increased significantly under the New Order. There are now at least one or two newspapers in each province, and two or three private radio stations. In Jakarta itself, there are four television channels run by private companies, compared with two government television channels. In addition, the public is not prohibited from having parabola antennae to access world information network by satellite. Transportation has also connected villages and small towns and opened up remote areas. It is believed that many sub-district capitals that used to be small and isolated, have now become medium-sized towns with a relatively high rate of mobility for the population.

The Indonesian economy has been forced to adjust to international economic change. Rising global economic competition and difficulties in obtaining international loans have forced the government to change some of its economic policies. For example, in fiscal policy, the government has had to reschedule a number of large projects. Meanwhile, state-owned companies are now open to market competition, operating with smaller subsidies from the government. Foreign investors have been given more freedom to invest over longer time periods and without the need to have local partners. Even more significantly, the government has tried to mobilize tax revenues through a reformed tax law in the wake of a shortfall in oil revenues. Tax campaigns are often launched to ensure that liable companies and individuals pay tax. Every year, the government publishes lists of individuals and companies paying the largest amount of tax in order to encourage people to pay taxes.

Various changes have been made to monetary policy, one being to allow the private sector to establish banks. As a result, many private banks are now existence, many of them with connections to big businesses. International banking is also promoted in Indonesia. Similar changes have taken place in investment policy, where more openness to foreign investment has been initiated. Foreign investment previously faced several limitations, as enforced by so-called government regulation No. 20/1994. In 1994, however, the government allowed foreign companies to invest in Indonesia without time limitations. The changes in fiscal as well as monetary and investment policies have made the government more dependent on society which, in turn, means that the window to democratization is now opened.

(Continued on title : "The Politics of Openness")


Tuesday, September 4, 2012

The Case of Indonesia's New Order

Why has the process of democratization in Indonesia been so slow despite fast economic growth? What are some of the important factors that have accounted for this situation? This chapter attempts to answer these questions.

Indonesia under the New Order has had at least two periods of quasi-democracy. The first was during the early years of the New Order (1966-74), and the second commenced from 1988. In the period 1966-74, Indonesia experienced what a noted Indonesian journalist Mochtar Lubis called a blossoming of freedom (Kompas, 8 March 1992). Power was shared among various power centres, and freedom of the press and expression was allowed. However, this period ended when students from various universities in Jakarta started to protest against the goverment.

The first protest occurred in 1968 against the increase in the price of rice and resulted in the government regulating the price along with the establishment of logistics bodies (Bulog or Badan Urusan Logistik) to regulate the distribution of rice and some other basic commodities. The second protest involved student demonstrations in 1974 against visiting Japanese Prime Minister Tanaka on the role of Japanese investment in Indonesia and the rest of Asia. This protest was known as the Malari affair. All these protests were not handled by the government through participatory measures but by political engineering which tended to decrease public political participation (Mas'oed 1989; Muhaimin 1980; Sumitro1991; Budiman 1991).

 Learning from the above incidents, the government tightened its grip during the period 1975-88. Critics were no longer tolerated, and the press were forced not to publish any news considered by the government as dangerous and which would threaten political stability. This policy of reducing political participation was supported by some leading economists who viewed stability as crucial to economic development. During the regime of Soekarno, the economy was in dire straits and by 1965 inflation was spiralling to over 600 per cent. Some argue that such a situation occurred because of government policies that gave too much attention to politics.

The 1980s can be viewed as a period in the development of Indonesian politics under the New Order government. During this decade and beyond there were hopes for an acceleration of the democratic process since the government began to introduce what it called keterbukaan politik (political openness). However although political liberalization has been affected, some remain sceptical about how far it will go and whether democratization can be felt by the people in their daily lives? There are some who believe that the position of the state remains much stronger vis-a-vis society, although there have been much progress in social and economic conditions. If this is the case what factors are behind this situation? Or, why is the present state of Indonesia still categorized as semi-authoritarian in the midst of social and economic progress? To answer these questions, it will be necessary to describe the present economic and political situation.

(Continued on title : "The Growth of the Economy")

Saturday, September 1, 2012

My Art


It started from boredom as I faced a canvas or support, because it looked like I was merely led by habit and my eyes when it came to the use of colors, lines, composition, theme, all the techniques and effects. There were times when all I wanted was to tear it apart and walk away from it.

From there I continued to seek what and how is painting. I tried to read books on fine art. But these only added to my frustration. Everything has already been discovered and our seniors have done it first. I don't have to follow form, since there was Delacroix, Manet, Monet, or Seurat. I don't have to pursue lines, for there have been Durer, Matisse, Miro or Oesman Effendi. I don't have to seek content, because I know Van Gogh, Gauguin, Dali, Rusli or Amang Rahman. Not to mention geniuses like Michelangelo, Da Vinci, Picasso, Kandinsky, Mondrian and Paul Klee.

My journey came to something in 1991. I concluded that somehow painting is about pouring out or putting into images what one feels inside, borrowing forms from nature or from 'the inside', from within ourselves.
I started anew from there. I began to think up ideas and then adopted the habit of making little sketches as a medium that could fit into the shoes of a painter. Afterward I pour my attention into anything I can find as the 'canvas' to say whatever I feel and think, honestly and freely: a canvas, scraps of used paper, walls, blackboards, even diaries.

My journey continues until today. I started to feel how good it is to 'paint', not just 'making paintings'. I do not care about forms, lines, composition, techniques, or any -ism within the fine art world. I paint on anything, with anything, using whatever technique, about anything that's there inside me when I am face-to-face with something to paint on. I believe that when I am hungry then whatever I paint is going to sing the tunes of hunger. When I am alone, silent, soft, dark, restless, choked, or screaming, whatever I paint would say it honestly and becomes the medium that channels the feeling without hesitation. I do not need themes, contents, or messages to transmit through my art. I do not see beauty and order as the ultimate priority. Good or bad, pretty or ugly, it is my painting, it is what I feel, it is what I want it to be.

A canvas or support becomes a kind of basket that hosts every idea, complaint, hope, howl, or hopelessness that is put into it sincerely.

The graffiti we can find anywhere, on the city walls, the bridges, scraps of paper, engraving on trees, often force us to smile, to get upset, to be embarrassed, to grunt, to be moved into tears, or at least force us to raise eyebrows.

Those things make me feel like I am not alone.

Ugo Untoro, 1997

The Typologies of Realism


by Liu Feng and Zhang Ruizhuang

Much more than a single theory, realism is a school of thought containing numerous related branches. In recent years an outpour of debate and exchange within the realist tradition has captured the attention of scholars. Many scholars have attempted to create schemes classifying the different branches and threads of realist thought that have emerged, while others have introduced a wealth of new terminology. Unfortunately, as a result of these efforts, realist concepts have become obfuscated, resulting in much confusion, and ultimately erecting a barrier to intellectual progress in the field. The goal of this article is to help remove this barrier by clarifying the criteria for classifying different approaches to realist thought and presenting a more coherent classification scheme that will enhance the understanding of the relationship between various strands of realist thought.

The Debate Regarding the Classification of Type of Realism

Since the 1980s, a number of new schools of thought, including constructivism, critical theory and post-modernism, have critiqued, and ultimately come to challenge, traditional schools of international relations theory such as realism and liberalism. Yet, as a result of sharp differences with respect to ontology, epistemology and methodology, exchange between these new schools and the more traditional mainstream schools have been quite limited. In stark contrast with this dearth of scholarly exchange across schools of thought, the intellectual debate and exchange of ideas within the realist school have flowered, giving birth to many new branches and sub-branches of realist thought.

Against the backdrop of this debate within the realist school, comparison and analysis of its different branches have moved to the forefront of research in international relations. The attention given to this debate by scholars across the world has deepened research on realism. These researches have dealt with developing the logic of the new strands of thought, testing them empirically, comparing them, or studying the relationship between new strands and traditional realism or structural realism. In broader terms, some researches have also focused on investigating the implications of this debate for the overall influence of realism on the discipline of international relations, especially with respect to whether the evolution of realist thought represents a step forward or a step backward with respect to our understanding of international relations.

But while this debate has contributed to the accumulation of knowledge and to intellectual progress, more recent research on this debate also demonstrates that it has also lead to the obfuscation of many concepts, and has created much confusion between scholars. Scholars have different focal points in their research, and different views on how to classify and understand the relationship between these new branches. This has lead to many attempts to restate viewpoints and assumptions, and to introduce many new concepts in order to clarify different theories. As Glen Snyder points out, there are now, in the field of contemporary international relations, at least two types of structural realism; potentially three types of offensive realism, not to mention numerous brands of defensive realism. In addition, there is neo-classical realism, contingent realism, specific realism, general realism and numerous other realisms. Michael Doyle, in his attempt to synthesize the intellectual history of international relations, further finds four distinct traditions within realism: Thucydides’ complex realism, Machiavelli's fundamentalist realism, Hobbes’ structural realism and Rousseau's constitutional realism. Doyle further argues that later development of realism was divided into these four different traditions of political thought.

On the one hand, that there are so many different strands of realist thought reflects the tremendous amount of disagreement between scholars working within the realist school. Yet on the other, this is also indicative of some difficulties and misconceptions that are held by various realist scholars, particularly with respect to how to identify and classify the different strands of realism. From the perspective of maintaining theoretical coherency, casually assigning labels tends to obscure the connection between different theories, exaggerating differences between different branches of theory. By introducing many concepts that are really not necessary, learning and understanding the theories become increasingly difficult. As a result, creating a scientific, coherent classification of the many branches of thought that have poured out of the realist camp stands to aid in clarifying and increasing understanding of this important school of international relations theory. In addition, as the different strands of realism are much more amenable to comparison with one another than with comparisons across different schools of IR theory, clarifying concepts and breaking down barriers stands to improve a dialogue between realists that stands to generate much progress in the field.

There are several established criteria for classifying theories within a mature school of thought in international relations. It is possible to group theories with respect to their central theoretical concept, their main assumptions or according to the units of analysis employed in the theory. For example, classifying according to main assumptions and general themes, it is generally held that the liberalist school can be divided into republican liberalism, economic liberalism, cognitive liberalism, social liberalism and institutional liberalism. Constructivism can be divided into identity-centred constructivism, norm-centred constructivism, and speech-act-oriented constructivism when classifying according to core theoretical concepts. Using units of analysis, Kenneth Waltz divides international relations theory into three images: that of man, state and system. Although Waltz's classification is rather broad—so much that it goes beyond any single intellectual tradition in international relations, a similar type of classification could be made for any given theoretical school.

In contrast to the clarity and precision associated with the classifications used in other schools of IR thought, the classifications that scholars have used for the realist school are vague and imprecise. Take for example, John Mearsheimer's attempt to distinguish between the three different branches of realism: human nature realism, offensive realism and defensive realism. Human nature realism can be seen as distinct in terms of its theoretical assumptions, or in terms of its units of analysis, yet offensive and defensive realism are distinguished in terms of an assumption with respect to states’ demands for power. Such a classification obviously lacks a unifying criterion linking the three branches together. According to the criterion that Mearsheimer uses with respect to states’ demand for power, Morgenthau's classical (human nature) realism should be classified as offensive realism, as Morgenthau contends that states seek to maximize their power. On the other hand, when employing level of analysis as the main criterion, both Mearsheimer's offensive realism and Waltz's defensive realism should be classified as structural realism, as both emphasize the international system and its structural restrictions on the behaviour of states.

The classifications used by other scholars are obviously also a source of misunderstanding in the discipline. For example, Stephen Brooks divides modern realism into neo-realism and post-classical realism, while Gideon Rose uses the categories neo-realism and neo-classical realism. The terminology used by these two scholars are very similar, so much so that without careful attention to the way that these scholars use these terms, one might conclude that Brooks and Gideon's typologies are analogous. In reality though, their classifications could not be more different. Brooks uses ‘post-classical realism’ to refer to defensive realism, while he uses the term ‘neo-realism,’ for which scholars already have a generally accepted definition, to describe the entirely different notion of offensive realism. Rose on the other hand uses neo-classical realism to represent scholarship that emphasizes the domestic level of analysis.

As is readily apparent from the above discussion, using different or inconsistent criteria to classify branches of theory, or inconsistent terminology can create misunderstandings which adversely affect scholarly debate. It is necessary to carefully consider the different classifications of realism, clarify the standards that should be used to create such classifications and proceed by establishing a coherent classification system. Through the synthesis of realist scholarship, this article identifies and discusses four dimensions according to which realist theories should be classified and through analysis of the current classification systems employed, it further clarifies the criteria that should be employed for consistently classifying branches of realist thought.

As we will argue below, unit of analysis and types of independent variables, dependent variables and theoretical assumptions are the best criteria to use when constructing a typology of realism. Using the first of these criteria (unit of analysis and independent variables), we show that realist thought can be divided into three branches: human nature realism, state-centric realism and system-centric realism. Using the second, dependent variables, we identify two broad categories of phenomena that theories of realism attempt to explain: theory of international politics and theory of foreign policy. Associated with this first category is structural realism, while neo-classical realism's focus is on the latter. Introducing the third of our criteria, theoretical assumptions, a major distinction is identified with respect to assumptions regarding whether countries seek security or power. These assumptions point to an important division within both structural realism and neo-classical realism: that between defensive and offensive realism. Finally, one additional classification can be made with respect to theoretical assumptions. As there are different understandings within realism with respect to the nature of the international system, a distinction can be made between balance of power realism and hegemonic realism. We argue, however, that this distinction should not be a basis for classifying types of realism, and that a consistent typology should limit itself to the preceding three dimensions.

This article turns next to introducing each of these criteria for classifying realist theories, and discussing each of the branches identified above. It also discusses linkages between the different criteria and addresses the coherency of this type of classification.

Man, State and System : Three Images of Realism

In Kenneth Waltz's classic, Man, the State and War, Waltz shows that all of the various explanations for the causes of war can be easily filtered into three images: that of man, the state and the international system. While Waltz was less concerned with creating a typology, and more interested in making progress with respect to understanding the reasons for the causes of war, his work demonstrates the power of classifying theories with respect to units of analysis. The selection of a particular unit of analysis reflects a core concern of theory building: the selection of the independent variable. The unit of analysis reflects to a great degree the independent variable that is selected in the theorization of a particular casual relationship. As the purpose of theory is to explain a casual relationship and describe a casual mechanism using the casual variables, it is natural that the unit of analysis be the starting point for a classification of realist theories.

Applying Waltz's logic to the realist camp, distinct categories of explanations can be readily identified. For example, traditional realism, with its emphasis on individuals, explains international phenomena and state behaviour from the point of view that human nature is intrinsically evil. Structural realism on the other hand throws out this assumption, and conducts an analysis based on the objective nature of the international structure, a system-level analysis. From the perspective of units of analysis, the different casual stories told by realist thinkers can be divided into three distinct categories: human nature realism, state-centric realism and system-centric realism.

Human nature realism, also known as biological realism, emphasizes man's biological abilities and intrinsically evil nature. Most classical realists (including the many modern political philosophers who have contributed to the development of realist thought), including especially Machiavelli, Herbert Butterfield, Reinhold Niebuhr, and Hans Morgenthau fall into this category. Morgenthau's theory is the best example of human nature realism in international relations. In Politics Among Nations, Morgenthau presents a systematic discussion of the basic principles of realism. The first of these principles consists of an assumption regarding the role of human nature in politics: politics ‘is governed by the objective laws that have their root in human nature.’ In Morgenthau's view, ‘political man is a selfish animal, and all human behaviour tends towards the control of others.’ As a result, battles over power are rooted in human nature and as such are central to politics.

State-centric realism looks for explanations for international relations phenomena and state behaviour from the vantage point of individual states (including national attributes, national interests and domestic politics). It is generally thought that realism does not concern domestic aspects of politics, or that consideration of such domestic issues represents a step away from realism's core concerns. This type of view though represents an obvious misunderstanding of realism. A careful look at the origins of realism, before Waltz's theory of international political systems, shows that most theorists in the realist camp focused their efforts on the level of the individual or of the state. Gilpin, for example, refers to himself as a state-centric realist scholar. In the field of international political economy, he contends that state interests and policies hinge on the governing political elite, on the pressures of powerful groups within a national society and on the nature of the ‘national system of political economy’. The neo-classical realism that has been popularized more recently argues even more explicitly that individual states should be integrated into the theories of foreign policy. Scholars working to these ends have attempted to establish a connection between the state and system-levels of analysis, and have emphasized the role of domestic factors in explaining how state behaviour leads to outcomes at the system level. From the writings of the mainstream neo-classical realists, states are still treated as the determining factors in the analysis of foreign policy and state behaviour, thus these theories are considered to be ‘second image’ theories.

System-centric realism sees the state of anarchy in the international system as its core theoretical building block, and looks here for the roots of state behaviour. There is a long tradition of scholarship that considers the implications of anarchy in the international system. Hobbes’ ‘state of nature’ can be seen as the definitive statement of this branch of realist theory. Even though Hobbes’ philosophical viewpoints maintain assumptions regarding human nature, realist theorists of international relations still borrow heavily from and attempt to extend his systematic description of the state of nature. John Hertz’ explication of the ‘security dilemma,’ for example, is based on Hobbesian logic of anarchy. Waltz similarly raised this notion of anarchy to the core of international relations theory, and created a systemic theory of realism with the international system as its core concern. From these efforts, structural realism emerged.

To illustrate the utility of using units of analysis to classify different theories, we next analyse the disagreement between scholars over the security dilemma. It turns out that realist scholars working within each of the different ‘images’ have different understandings of this concept. First conceptualized by John Hertz, the security dilemma was defined as a social state in which individual powers have no authority above them to enforce behavioural norms or to prevent them from attacking one another. Within this state, mutual suspicion and fear drive individual states to obtain more security by increasing their power. From this definition it can be seen that the roots of the security dilemma are found in the state of anarchy, under which individual states lack the protection of a higher authority. Thus, it is not surprising that when Hertz proposed the security dilemma, he explicitly rejected the human nature element; that is to say regardless of whether human nature is peaceful and cooperative, or domineering and aggressive, is not the question.

Yet, departing from Hertz, Butterfield conceives of this ‘Hobbesian fear’ as man's inherent ‘original sin,’ or as an imperfection rooted in human nature. Butterfield then finds the individual level, or the ‘first image’ to be at the core of the security dilemma.

In recent years, a number of realist scholars have re-considered the security dilemma from the perspective of domestic politics, and proposed revisions to the theory. Of particular importance, the neo-classical realist, Charles Glaser added two non-structural variables when he analysed the implications of the security dilemma: the extent of the adversary's greed and the adversary's unit-level knowledge of the state's motives. Glaser pointed out that if competitors seek not only security, but also have grander desires, competitive policies can cause other countries to give up these other desires and help to avoid conflicts. If adversaries understand the motivation of other powers, it will permit some cooperative policies to be possible, and help to prevent the security dilemma from occurring.

As to which of the three different statements of the security dilemma seems more plausible, this question is beyond the scope of this article. What can be seen from this discussion though is that because the units of analysis and logical starting points are different, realist theorists have different understandings of the origins of the security dilemma, and as a result, there are a wide array of different theoretical extensions and conclusions that are the subject of much debate.

At present, of the three images of realism, the great brunt of this debate takes place between the second and the third images, while realism has largely evolved to render the first image a historical artefact. After the behaviouralist revolution, realist theory became much more scientific, and moved beyond making assumptions about human nature that are impossible to observe or verify, instead absorbing only the more suitable components of human nature realism. In recent years, many debates have flourished around system outcomes and their unit-level determinants. Regardless of whether one looks within or outside of the realist school, more and more theorists have started to emphasize the relationship between the system and its individual units. However, despite this work, there has yet to be a successful attempt at compacting the two into one systematic theory.

Before concluding this section it is important to make a final note regarding the use of unit of analysis as a criterion for classifying realist theories. What we are classifying are not particular theorists, but rather their theories. Any given theorist most likely works on a fairly wide range of problems spanning several different fields, and they will often make different assumptions, or develop theories employing different units of analysis depending on their research questions. Take Waltz as an example—his theory of structural realism obviously belongs to the category of system-centric realism. However, in his book Foreign Policy and Democratic Politics, he compares the differences between American and British foreign policy from the perspective of their domestic political structures with an eye towards crafting a theory of foreign policy. To give another example, Gilpin emphasizes in his work on international political economy that his is a state-centric approach, but yet his theory of hegemonic transitions would be more appropriately classified as system-centric realism. Thus, from the perspective of unit of analysis, it is only possible to complete a rather loose classification of theories, and not a classification of theorists. Further, within each level, the independent variables that scholars select will vary.

Two Directions of Theory Buildings : Theory of International Politics and Theory of Foreign Policy


Scholarly efforts in international relations consist of work in two distinct, but related fields: international politics and foreign policy. Generally speaking, international politics consists of the study of the interactions of three or more states and the outcomes of these interactions. Foreign policy research on the other hand, deals with a particular state and its motivations, policies, directives and behaviour with respect to international affairs. From the perspective of theory building, there are several commonalities in these two areas: first, both the theories are built on the basis of discovery or recognition of patterns; second, theories represent a claim with respect to a casual relationship that explains the empirical patterns. On the other hand, within each respective field, the breadth and scope of phenomena to be explained, as well as the applicability of different theories differ.

Waltz has made a systematic explication of the differences between these two fields. In his view, international politics studies international outcomes that are a result of the behaviour of individual states and interactions between states, which can tell us about the external environment and pressures faced by a state. Foreign policy on the other hand researches the specific behaviours of states to determine how states respond to external pressure. Waltz further distinguishes these two types of theories using the analogy of the differences between theory of markets and theory of the firms in the discipline of microeconomics.

Fareed Zakaria is an example of one scholar who attempts to build theories of foreign policy. He applauds Waltz's point of view, agreeing that theory of foreign policy explains the intent and objectives of states, as well as trends with respect to how states face the external environment, but does not speak of outcomes. This is so because whether a state's efforts are successful depends on the external environment, particularly the objectives and capabilities of other countries.

Summing the above points of view, we argue that theory of international politics explains the frequently occurring phenomena and basic types of behaviour, such as the continuous occurrence of war, the constant emergence of the balance of power or the replacement of hegemons; theory of foreign policy, on the other hand, explains the motivations and behaviours of particular states, for example, the circumstances under which a state forms an alliance or when it chooses to expand. Theory of international politics is considered grand or general theory, while theory of foreign policy is more accurately considered middle range or local theory. The distinction across these two fields actually reflects differences between what each theory is trying to explain, that is, the differences between the dependent variables of interest. This becomes our second criteria for classifying theories of realism.

Many realist scholars, including Morgenthau, Waltz and Gilpin, are engaged in the development of grand or general theories, of which structural realism is perhaps the best example. These theories are considered theories of international politics, and the scope of what they explain includes re-occurring or important phenomena in the international system (of course, this does not preclude these theorists from analysing, evaluating or predicting the state's foreign policy). To demonstrate why these are general theories, it is helpful to consider Waltz's defence of the balance of power theory. Waltz's statement of the balance of power is a widely criticized portion of his theory of structural realism, particularly in the post-Cold War period, when the international power structure obviously had lost its balance, but where all of the major powers did not expand their military resources or attempt to form alliances to hedge against the US power. Critics of Waltz argue that structural realism's balance of power theory has no way of explaining or predicting post-Cold War international politics, or the actions of states in the post-Cold War period. Considering the difference between theory of international politics and theory of foreign policy, it becomes immediately apparent that these arguments do not represent valid critiques of Waltz. As structural realism's balance of power theory is a structural theory, the balance does not depend on the conscious balancing activities of individual states. Waltz's theory instead explains and predicts the balance of power, a commonly observed objective phenomena, using structural analysis of the system, and not a unit-level analysis of the states’ balancing strategies. Because states will always deploy varied strategies to survive, sometimes employing balancing strategies, while other times aligning with a major power, the specific type of strategy that is deployed depends on the circumstances. Thus, these theories never aim to predict individual outcomes at the local level. Instead, the focus is on the overall trend towards a balance of power in the international system.

Some scholars raise objections to this distinction between theory of international politics and theory of foreign policy, arguing that the two are not entirely distinct. These scholars hold that one theory can explain both broad international phenomena and individual state behaviour. Representative of this view is Colin Elman, who counters Waltz by arguing that neo-realism should not pigeon hole itself as theory of international politics. Using a colourful analogy, he argues that the neo-realist ‘horse’ should be let to run on both the course of theory of international politics as well as the course of theory of foreign policy, regardless of whether it wins or loses. Waltz countered by arguing that his old horse absolutely cannot run on the course of theory of foreign policy, and if it tries, it is certain to lose. Elman's argument, however, does not seem so unreasonable, particularly as its original intent was to develop neo-realism's research agenda and expand the space within which it is able to explain and predict.

In order to better understand this debate between Waltz and Elman, it is important to bring to mind the difference between theory building and theory application. It has already been pointed out elsewhere in the article that theory building is concerned with finding and explaining empirical patterns, research focusing on the patterns themselves. Application of theory, on the other hand, consists of using pre-existing theories to analyse particular cases, the focus of the research on a particular aspect or case of the pattern. For example, we can use structural realism to analyse the changing triangular relationship between the United States, Soviet Union and China during the 1960s and 1970s. This theory can tell us about certain trends and deeper causes of the adjustment of Chinese foreign policy and the Sino–US rapprochement during that period, as the changing relations between the three countries fit the general pattern predicted by balance of power theory—that these changes are a result of the shift in the distribution of power taking place at the time. However, structural realism has no way of explicating the detailed movements, policy adjustments or process of re-alignment that occurred during the warming of relations between China and the United States, nor can it determine the specific timeline according to which their relationship would ultimately reach normalization. In order to arrive at a more detailed understanding of a state's foreign policy, we must investigate other factors beyond the distribution of power.

On the basis of this example, we can understand why Waltz maintained his opposition to structural realism as a theory of foreign relations. For Waltz, the international structure was a constraining, not a determining factor of state behaviour. Through competition and adaptation amongst states, structural pressure asserted its effects, causing states with similar levels of power to trend towards the same types of behaviour over the long term. Only under very rare circumstances could the international structure be a determining factor in specific foreign policy or foreign behaviours of states. Generally, international structural pressure and foreign policy output is mediated by domestic factors. In order for the theory to be able to make correct descriptions and accurate predictions of the foreign policy of specific states at specific points in time, many additional variables must be considered (i.e. we must engage in theory building, and not just application). Yet, not only will the introduction of these variables detract from the parsimony of the theory itself, but it will also eliminate the ability of it to generalize as a theory of international politics. It is for these reasons then that we argue that structural realism is a theory of international politics, and a tool that we can use to aid our understanding of foreign policy. However, attempting to apply theory of international politics to foreign policy analysis does not imply that it is also a theory of foreign policy.

That said, there is one disadvantage in Waltz pigeon-holing structural realism as a theory of international politics. Limiting structural realism in this way rejects the possibility of developing a system-level theory of foreign policy. We realize that structural realism as a research programme has two central components or ‘hard cores’. First, it is a system-level theory, second, its primary variable is power distribution. Changing either of these components, for example, adding a unit-level variable, or replacing distribution of power with distribution of identity will cause structural realism to morph into another kind of research programme. However, if we can discover new empirical patterns of state behaviour, foreign policy, interactions between states or the international outcomes affected by these phenomena, and if we can still explain them in terms of the power structure, this will not change the core concern of structural realism. Instead, this is a valid extension of the original theory, and a way of taking structural realism and developing it from a single core theory into a full-blown research programme. This is also to say that insofar as a strong casual relationship can be established between structural causes and foreign policy, neo-realism can develop into a theory of foreign policy.

Within the social sciences, the goal of theoretical research is to look for patterns in behaviour and outcomes, and to explain the casual relationships and casual mechanisms found in such patterns. According to these criteria, we argue that foreign policy research is a field where few theories have been discovered. The debates in this field have been more about the research methods, analytical frameworks and strategies that should be applied to foreign policy research. As a result, in western universities, courses in this field tend to have titles such as ‘Foreign policy analysis.’ Generally, when one speaks of the theory of foreign policy, it is understood as ‘theory’ only in the most general sense.

The difficulty of creating theories in foreign policy research stems from two factors. First, when scholars research foreign policy, they tend to focus on a specific policy process or outcome, which results in the variables becoming context-specific, only suitable for research of one particular case. Second, many different factors at different levels affect the process of policy selection, decision-making and implementation, yet, theory cannot simply be a description of all of these factors. Instead, it must consider the logic relationship between many different variables and opportunely distill them into a system with tight logic. The need to go through this later process highly increases the difficulty of creating theories that can account for foreign policy behaviour. It is important to note though that the different units in international relations can all be theorized to different degrees, as phenomena can always be abstracted into a pattern at some level.

Within the realist school, the primary branch that has emerged over the past several years that is concerned with the construction of theories of foreign policy is what Gideon Rose terms ‘neo-classical realism.’ According to Rose, scholars conducting research within this branch of realism include Randall Schweller, Fareed Zakaria, William C. Wohlforth and Thomas J. Christensen. These scholars do not agree that there is a need for a separation between the internal domestic and external environmental components of state's foreign policy, nor do they intend to construct a general theory with respect to international politics. Instead their core concern is with explaining the foreign policy behaviour of particular states. The policies and behaviours they are concerned with include: grand strategy, military policy, international economic policy, trends in alliances and crisis management. The fundamental tenets of neo-classical realism are that foreign policy is an outcome of international structure, domestic factors and of a complex interaction between the two. Even though state power and the position of states in the international system are determining factors in the selection of foreign policy, at the same time domestic factors can also affect foreign policy. The roles played by system effects and unit-level factors in foreign policy outcomes are considerably different. If system effects are considered as the independent variables, unit-level factors are the intervening variables connecting foreign policy and the international system—they have the effect of strengthening or weakening the influence of structural factors on unit behaviour. Having clarified the effects of system and unit-level variables, these scholars then focus their efforts on the unit factors in the making and implementation of foreign policy.

The theory of neo-classical realism attempts to resolve a major problem in international relations research. We know that neo-realism's successful construction of a macro-theory at the system level has had a tremendous amount of influence on later theoretical research. In similar fashion, for example, Robert Keohane and Alexander Wendt, respectively brought liberalism and constructivism to the system level. At present, the three major schools of international relations are all system-level theories. This state of affairs has caused many scholars to become disaffected, and regardless of whether one looks within the realist, liberalist or constructivist school, there is opposition to the separation between ‘system and unit’ and ‘structure and process’. How to build a bridge between these two and establish a multilevel theory remains a major problem within international relations research. The pathbreaking research in neo-classical realism has much potential with respect to overcoming this difficultly. If at the centre of the theory are casual relationships and casual mechanisms, then it is imperative that the place and effect of different variables in the casual chain are made distinct. This is precisely the task which neo-classical realist scholars have focused on in their work.

That said, theorizing in neo-classical realism is in need of advancement. As of present, the questions and variables are too numerous, and it is still not possible to find a central explanatory variable at the unit level. Right now, it is only possible to conduct a case analysis of the foreign policy history of a single country, which lacks generalizability. Neo-classical realism is not yet a unified theoretical programme, as many scholars put forth a wide range of domestic-level variables such as national intentions, knowledge of policy makers, domestic political structure, offensive/defensive balance, etc. As to which of these variables is most important for foreign policy making, scholars have yet to reach an agreement. If scholars can come to an understanding with respect to a core variable, and create more suitable research designs and empirical research projects, neo-classical realism will be able to be more robust and persuasive as an explanatory theory.

Offence and Defence : A Distinction between Security and Power

The distinction between offensive and defensive realism is one of the most well-known in the discipline. As early as 1991, Synder in his Myths of Empire differentiated between aggressive and defensive realism, which became the dividing line between the two distinct branches of thought that eventually emerged: offensive and defensive realism. From this point until the present, the debate between these two branches of realism has consistently been a central point of contention within the realist school.

At the centre of the distinction between offensive and defensive realism are different assumptions with respect to the way that states tend to behave within the context of anarchy. In more specific terms, it is a distinction with respect to whether states maximize security or power, that is to say, whether power is a means or an end. Some scholars contend that the primary goals that states seek to achieve are survival and security. For these scholars, power is a tool for achieving a goal, and not a goal in itself. Those holding this view are considered defensive realists. Another group of scholars, those that fall within the camp of offensive realism, assume that states seek power as both a means and as an end. This distinction between these types of assumptions is the third of our criteria for classifying branches of realism.

When distinguishing between offensive and defensive realism, scholars should strictly consider the theoretical assumptions of each theory. This point is particularly stressed as some scholarships have incorporated policy aspects into the distinction between the two branches. For example, scholars who have advocated deployment of offensive policies have been labelled by some as offensive realist thinkers, while others argue that the neo-conservative Bush Administration's use of pre-emptive strategy and unilateralism represent offensive realism. These viewpoints incorrectly establish a connection between academic arguments and foreign policy thinking of individual governments. The reality is that most realists, regardless of whether they are offensive or defensive are in opposition to the United States’ aggressive policy position.

It is also important to avoid abstract discussions with respect to offensive and defensive realism, as there are a number of differences of opinion within each of these threads of realist theory. To take offensive realism as an example, all of the scholars within this camp argue that states maximize their power, and further contend that states tend towards aggressive policies. However, with respect to national attribute and behaviour, there are considerable differences found in the literature. Schweller argues that the attributes of states can be either status-quo or revisionist, and that bandwagoning with the superpowers tends to be the common type of behaviour. Mearsheimer, on the other hand, contends that it is very difficult to find a status-quo state in international politics, as the anarchical nature of the international system has left most states with a security deficit. In this view then, the more common type of state behaviour is ‘buck passing.’

Both scholars start from the same assumption that states maximize power, yet arrive at vastly different conclusions. Why might this be the case? This is because Schweller considers several unit-level factors, thereby changing the logic behind the theory. Schweller critiques Waltz for being biased towards the status-quo, and advocates instead that ‘the revisionist state should be brought back in to research’. For Schweller, the critical difference between the two types of states is their level of satisfaction with their position in the international system. However, we know that whether a state is satisfied is a variable: a country might uphold the status-quo at one point in time, while attempting to change it during another. Thus, it is not a fixed characteristic of a state, and as such it is not appropriate to make assumptions with respect to state satisfaction. Furthermore, imputing a state's type as status-quo or revisionist based on observation of a particular behaviour is tautology. As for Mearsheimer, his statement that ‘there are no status-quo states in the international system’ will not be discussed here. It is sufficient to say that this theory is logically consistent, regardless of whether it is appropriate.

Within the defensive realist camp, similar differences are found. For example, Waltz describes the competition for security within the context of anarchy in terms of the Hobbesian state of nature. In his view, there is a lack of security in the international system, and states always have anxiety with respect to their existence. Waltz's theory relies on the assumptions of anarchy and that states seek survival, and his internal logic is consistent. Other scholars do not emphasize the state of anarchy and the security dilemma, arguing instead that security is not in short supply. They see states as having adequate security, primarily as they make several assumptions with respect to domestic factors. Scholars that do emphasize the state of anarchy argue that if states want to maintain their position within the international system, the ideal policy is to maintain the balance of power. Those scholars that do not place much emphasis on the state of anarchy argue that states should maintain a balance between offensive and defensive in their weapons technology, and that they can maintain security through cooperation.

From this discussion it can be seen that whether a state seeks security or power depends on a theoretical assumption, which must be considered together with other assumptions. As this is the case, offensive and defensive realism do not necessarily represent independent branches of the realist school. Instead, it is much more logical to consider them as sub-branches of neo-realism and neo-classical realism.

As several scholars have pointed out, the offence–defence debate is actually found within both neo-realism and neo-classical realism. To make clear the full extent of the differences between offensive and defensive realism, we must also consider the divide between neo-realism and neo-classical realism. Following this logic, Jeffrey W. Taliaferra has demarcated the main theories (or assumptions) within realism (Table 1).


Table 1
Categories of Offensive and Defensive Realism
Assumptions about Anarchy
Phenomena to be explainedDefensive realismOffensive realism
(The international system provides incentives for expansion only under certain circumstances)(International system always provides incentives for expansion)
Neo-realismBalance-of-power theory (Kenneth Waltz);Hegemonic theory of war (Robert Gilpin);
(Theories that seek to explain international outcomes—for example, the likelihood of great power war, the durability of alliances or the likelihood of international cooperation)Dynamic differentials theory (Dale Copeland); Great power cooperation theories (Robert Jervis, Charles Glaser, Benjamin Miller)Power transition theory (A.F.K. Organski and Jack Kugler); Balance of interests theory (Randall Schweller); Theory of great power politics (John Mearsheimer)
Neo-classical realismBalance-of-threat theory (Stephen Walt);
(Theories that seek to explain the external behaviour of individual states—for example, military doctrine force posture, alliance preferences, foreign economic policy or the pursuit of accommodative or belligerent diplomacy)Domestic mobilization theory (Thomas Christensen); Offence–defence theories (Stephen Van Evera, Thomas Christensen, Jack Synder, Charles Glaser and Chaim Kaufmann)State-centred realism (Freed Zakaria); Theory of war aims (Eric Labs); Hegemonic theory of foreign policy (William Wohlforth)



Although the arguments and theories of at least one scholar are not properly classified in this table (for example, Taliaferra places Schweller's balance of interests theory into the neo-realist category; however, according to the scholar's own claims, and the general consensus among other scholars, this should be placed under neo-classical realism), the table reflects rather clearly the relationship between the classifications of offensive/defensive realism and level of analysis/scope of explanation, as discussed previously.

As shown earlier, the major differences between offensive and defensive realism are found in their different assumptions. Besides this though, the two theories also disagree with respect to the implications of anarchy, the survival strategy of states and their method of behaviour. In order to make these differences in the branches of realism easier to grasp, we have unpacked the categories in Taliaferra's classification, while maintaining the general scheme (Table 2).


Table 2
A Comparison of the Differences across Different Branches of Realism
Neo-RealismNeo-classical Realism
Defensive RealismOffensive RealismDefensive RealismOffensive Realism
Phenomena explainedInternational outcomes and modes of behaviourInternational outcomes and modes of behaviourState policy and behaviourState policy and behaviour
Level of analysisSystemSystemStateState
AnarchyHobbesianHobbesianBenign; relatively peacefulUnclear; difficult to distinguish
Unit-level attributesNo differences across statesNo differences across statesDifferences such as geography, technology and knowledge are importantDistinction between status-quo and revisionist states (there is a contradiction here with the assumption regarding power maximization)
PowerMeans, not an end; seek sufficient powerMeans and an end, maximize powerMeans and not an end; maintain offensive/defensive balanceMeans and an end; maximization of power
Conclusion about state behaviourEnlightened national interests; maintain the balance of powerSeek hegemonic powerGreat powers cooperate; ‘buck passing’Expansion


Although the debate between offensive and defensive realism has attracted much attention recently, the dividing lines between the two are not consistent, as can be seen from the arguments made by many realists. As Waltz pointed out, realism is not offensive or defensive—all states use numerous means to preserve their existence. The use of an offensive or a defensive strategy is always determined by the specific context. Many scholars argue that Waltz's theory should be classified as defensive realism, yet he does not deny that states will expand their power when circumstances permit. He has also made it clear in the past that he believes that states’ objectives range from just seeking to exist on one end of a continuum to domination on the other. Mearsheimer also admits that states are not always under all circumstances seeking to maximize power. Although some states may trend towards the absolute pursuit of power, the pressures of the system will often prevent them from achieving maximization of power. This can be seen from his design of the grand strategy of the United States. In order to prevent other states from hedging against the US power, Mearsheimer advocates that the United States should engage in a strategic consolidation of its power, playing the role of an ‘offshore balancer’. Many realists, regardless of whether they are in the offensive or the defensive camp agree that this should be the role of the United States.

Prudent power and enlightened interest are the basic values of political realists. Morgenthau saw prudence as the supreme virtue of politics and thought that if states want to advance and protect their own interests, they must respect the interests of other states. Waltz also pointed out lucidly that power is merely a means that can be employed, and that sensible politicians pursue a moderate amount of power. The history of international relations offers many examples of states that pursued the expansion of power to the extremes, and in doing so, sowed the seeds for their own destruction. If it is conceded that the international structure is a restriction on the behaviour of states, then states cannot seek to expand power without limit. At a minimum, their motivations and behaviour, intentions and outcomes cannot be divorced from one another. Offensive realists such as Mearshemier who see states as seeking absolute power to great extremes, although they show the pessimism and drama of power politics, do not fall within realism's fundamental tradition of prudence and enlightenment.

Balance and Preponderance : The Two States of the International System

Realists have different understandings of the nature of the international system. More specifically there are two different types of descriptions, explanations and predictions with respect to the implications of a concentration or a diffusion of power. The first view holds that the international system generally maintains a balance of power, while the other holds that the normal state of the international system is a preponderance of power. Recently, scholars have termed these two points of view as balance-of-power realism and hegemonic realism. Jack Levy argues that many people link realism to the concept of a balance of power, but that, in fact, such a connection represents a conceptual misunderstanding. That almost all balance-of-power theorists are realists does not mean that all realists are balance-of-power theorists. Christopher Layne has pointed out that the debate over the ideas of balance of power and hegemony is a major fault line in the realist school.

In a series of papers, Levy introduced the distinction between balance of power and hegemony. According to Levy, balance-of-power realism holds that in order to guarantee their own survival, states within the international system (especially great powers) try to prevent hegemonic powers from emerging. When a great power acquires a predominant position in the international system, other powers will typically ally to balance against it. Although the system will on occasion be out of balance, it will tend towards a balance of power over the long-term. Great powers generally will balance, using both internal and external strategies, and in general will not ally with the hegemon. Classical realism, Waltz's neo-realism, offensive/defensive realism and neo-classical realism can all be considered types of balance-of-power realism, despite the fact that these various branches do not agree with respect to which states will seek to balance and under what conditions they will balance.

Hegemonic realism disagrees with this argument, holding that hegemonic powers tend to emerge in the international system. These powers will establish a set of political, economic and behavioural norms to manage the international system, a concentration of power thereby bringing stability to the system. This stability will waver and major wars will occur at the points when a new hegemon rises to challenge the hegemonic power and there is a period of hegemonic transition. This branch of theory includes power transition theorists such as Organski, as well as Gilpin's hegemonic stability theory and William Thompson's long cycle leadership theory.

In order to compare the differences between balance-of-power realism and hegemonic realism, we can use Levy's treatment of the two to identify three main differences. First, the two have different understandings of the basic nature of the international system and its operation. According to the balance-of-power theory, a balance is the natural state of the international system. Waltz goes as far as to claim that any theory of international politics, by definition has to be a balance-of-power theory. By this, he means that theory of international politics can only study regular patterns, and as balance of power is the only regularity within international politics, it is the only object of study. Hegemonic theorists on the other hand argue that the more common state of the international system is for a preponderant state to emerge and play the role of a leader in the international system.

Second, the two branches have different understandings of stability, war and peace in the international system. Balance-of-power theory contends that when the power of major states is relatively equal, the system maintains stability. Hegemonic theory on the other hand argues that there will be relatively little war between great powers when one hegemonic power controls the international system, and that under these circumstances stability is maintained with relative ease. Of course, there is again disagreement within each of these theories with respect to the number of poles in the system and its ability to remain stable, as well as regarding the system's ability to prevent war. For example, Morgenthau argues that a multipolar system is more stable, while Waltz maintains the view that a bipolar system is more stable.

Lastly, the two branches differ with respect to foreign policy and strategic decision making. Balance-of-power theory holds that states within the international system (especially great powers) will opt to maintain a rather weak position, and not establish linkages with the predominate power, that is to say, they will employ a balancing strategy; hegemonic theory on the other hand maintains that because hegemonic powers can maintain stability in the system, and provide public goods, that it is in the interest of other states to ‘chain-gang’ or align with the hegemon.

Even though the balance of power and hegemony represent two important categories within the realist school, we do not necessarily agree that this is the most suitable distinction to make. First, the goal of creating a typology of theories is to distinguish between independent branches of thought, and not to differentiate points of view. A point of view in itself cannot become a branch of theory. Only if a particular class of viewpoints shares a common theoretical core and the same basic assumptions can it be considered a branch of theory. Using this criterion to consider Levy's typology, we can see that within both balance-of-power theory and hegemonic theory there are many obvious differences. For example, he classifies classical realism, Waltz's neo-realism, offensive/defensive realism and neo-classical realism as balance-of-power realism, yet each of these theories has its own independent theoretical core and set of basic assumptions, and each can be considered its own branch of theory. With respect to the balance of power, the focal points of these theories are also not necessarily the same. Some of these study how the balance of power is formed through the distribution of power within the international system (Waltz's structural realism), while others study the balancing behaviour that states adopt (neo-classical realism), while yet others study both of these factors (classical realism). Similar complexity exists within the so-called class of hegemonic realisms, including power transition theory, hegemonic stability theory, and long cycle leadership theory, each of which also suggests different means of hedging against a hegemonic power. Levy clearly recognizes this as he notes ‘conceptions of power in terms of land-based military power in nearly all applications of balance of power theory should be contrasted with hegemonic stability theory's focus on financial and commercial strength, with power transition theory's measurement of power in terms of gross national product, and leadership long cycle theory's conception of power in terms of naval capability (at least until the 20th century) and dominance in leading economic sectors’.

Second, not only do the theories that are classified as balance-of-power realism or hegemonic realism not share similar core concerns and assumptions, but also the substance of what they study is also entirely different. Some focus on what is traditionally considered international politics, focusing on political and military affairs; while others are more concerned with international political economy, focusing on issues at the nexus of economics and politics. Hegemonic stability theory and long cycle leadership theory are two examples of theories that focus on the latter. As these theories are used to study different issues the two lack comparability.

Third, the evolution of the international system itself is a dynamic process within which balance-of-power and hegemony are two intermittent phases of its evolution. Maintaining consistent criteria to evaluate the two, it is impossible for the international system to be in both of these states at any given time. Whether the basic state of the international system is a balance or a preponderance of power can be distinguished. Any theory that studies the state of the international system should be able to explain both of these states, and the appearance of either state—for example, structural realism is able to explain the current unipolar system.

From the three points made above, it should be apparent that balance-of-power realism and hegemonic realism are both conceptually too broad, and that attempts to classify them within a typology of theories can only make realism even more difficult to understand. Thus, it does not seem that this distinction with respect to the nature of the international system is all that useful as a criterion for classifying realist theories.

Conclusion

Realism has a long intellectual tradition within the study of international relations, and it has already developed into a mature school of thought with several distinct branches of theory. In one respect, these different schools have enriched the realist school. Yet, they have also inevitably created difficulties with respect to classifying the different types of realist theory, leading to many different classification schemes and labels.

This article has analysed the problem of classifying contemporary realist thought with respect to four dimensions: unit of analysis, phenomena to be explained, assumptions with respect to the motivations of states and the state of the international system. We argue that the first three of these criteria can be accepted as valid criteria for classifying realist theories. The fourth of these, however, is too broad to distinguish between theories, and is not a suitable criterion against which to classify different branches of realist thought. With the first criteria, unit of analysis, this article has distinguished three types of realism: human nature realism, state-centric realism and system-centric realism. Using the criterion of phenomena to be explained, two further categories emerge: theory of international politics and theory of foreign policy, which are presently represented by neo-realism and neo-classical realism. The final criterion, assumptions regarding the motivation of states renders one last distinction between offensive and defensive realism. In opposition with the generally accepted view though, we argue that this offensive and defensive realism should be discussed within the framework of neo-realism and neo-classical realism.

In order to better understand the different criteria and the relationship and differences between the different branches of thought, we present a chart (Figure 1) rendering our typology. The chart is divided into quadrants based on differences in the dependent and independent variables. As Figure 1 indicates, the starting point for realism (independent variable) has two dimensions, system and unit, while the phenomena to be explained (dependent variable) consists of either international politics or foreign policy. Along these two dimensions, the various branches of realism are placed. After the independent and dependent variables for a particular branch of theory are determined, it can be placed in one of the quadrants on the graph, thus rendering clearly the different distinctions within the realist school.


Fig. 1
Figure. 1
Typologies of realism.


As can be seen from Figure 1, classifying realist theories according to the three criteria discussed above places them in several different positions on the chart. The empty space in the first and the fourth quadrants does not imply that there have been no attempts in the realist school to construct a state-level theory of international politics or a system-level theory of foreign policy. Rather, these are left blank as efforts in these two areas have yet to develop into mature branches of realism. It is likely that these two spaces represent the direction that realism will develop in the future. From this chart it can also be seen that it is not the case that the branches of realism distinguished by these criteria are unrelated. Instead they either intersect with or are subsumed within one another. Thus, before comparing or evaluating the relationship between different branches, it is important that the criteria are carefully noted.

One additional note is needed here. The aforementioned classification cannot necessarily incorporate all aspects of modern realism. The writings and contributions of some realist scholars cannot be confined within a single branch of realist theory, further, the various classification schemes might intersect or overlap. Naturally, in comparison with the recent careless use of labels, and new terminology, a precise set of classificatory criteria is very useful for explicating the core concerns and major distinctions made in the debate within the realist school, and is of further use with respect to providing a proper understanding of the different branches of realism. The accumulation of knowledge should pay careful attention to maintaining its continuity. It is not the case that every new distinction made or every intellectual innovation should become a new conceptual or theoretical system. Every time a realist scholar adds a new theoretical assumption it is not necessary to use a new label or term of reference for his idea, nor should the scholars’ attempts to classify or evaluate different ideas result in a proliferation of new terms, otherwise it could result in unnecessary obfuscation of concepts and misunderstanding. This article presents a preliminary analysis of the issues related to the classification of realism with an eye towards increasing awareness and debate of these issues, and on the basis of this, paves the path for the future development of the realist school.

(Reproduced from the Science of International Politics, with kind permission of the authors and the Institute of International Studies, Tsinghua University)
Powered By Blogger